I was interested to read
recently at the Huffington Post that John Makin, an economist at the
American Enterprise Institute (“AEI”), a conservative Washington, DC think
tank, had recently written that the U.S. was already on a deficit reduction
path and that there should not be more deficit reduction at the current time. Of
course, liberals like this message coming from a conservative, but, if one
reads Makin’s paper, there is much in it for liberals to dislike. The paper
does not appear, though, to be aimed at convincing liberals. It is aimed at a
different audience.
Before turning to this recent paper, I note that Paul
Krugman once praised John Makin in a post about an article Makin had written in
2010. The title of Krugman’s post was “John
Makin’s Hair Is On Fire.” Krugman
wrote that even though Makin is a political conservative at a “right-wing think
tank,” he had written “something I or Jan Hatzius (Goldman’s chief economist —
never mind the Blankfein stuff, the econ group is very good, and very
pessimistic) might have written. Except Makin is even more gloomy, warning that
we might enter deflation this year.”
The article to which Krugman was referring is a July 2010 Economic Outlook piece called “The Rising
Threat of Deflation.” It is worth
reading, and it certainly does not toe the line that austerity (“fiscal
consolidation”) is a good idea. At the
end of the article, Makin writes:
“The G20's shift toward rapid, global fiscal consolidation--a
halving of deficits by 2013--threatens a public sector, Keynesian ‘paradox of
thrift’ whereby because all governments are simultaneously tightening fiscal
policy, growth is cut so much that revenues collapse and budget deficits
actually rise. The underlying hope or expectation that easier money, a weaker
currency, and higher exports can somehow compensate for the negative impact on
growth from rapid, global fiscal consolidation cannot be realized everywhere at
once. The combination of tighter fiscal policy, easy money, and a weaker
currency, which can work for a small open economy, cannot work for the global
economy.
“The link between volatile financial conditions and the real
economy has been powerfully underscored by the events since mid-2007. Growth
has suffered and subsequently recovered given powerful monetary and fiscal
stimulus. And yet, the damaged financial sector, unable to supply credit; a
jump in the precautionary demand for cash; and a persistent overhang of global
production capacity have combined to leave deflation pressure intact. The G20's
newfound embrace of fiscal stringency only adds to the extant deflation
pressure.
“No wonder no country wants a strong currency anymore, as
attested to by Europe's easy acceptance of a weaker euro. The acute phase of
the financial crisis is over, but the chronic trend toward deflation that has
followed it is not.”
One can criticize Makin’s 2010 article for being overly
pessimistic; deflation has not happened. It was, though, a solid piece of
analysis of the risks. Unfortunately, one cannot say the same about the
analysis in his new Economic Outlook piece,
“Austerity
Undone” or his shorter Guardian article on the same
subject.
In “Austerity Undone,” he writes that the now-famous Carmen
Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff article implying that a 90 percent debt-to-GDP
ratio represents a danger point “has been shown to be seriously flawed.” He states that there are now doubts about both
“fiscal austerity” and “a resumption of Federal Reserve tightening.” After all,
“U.S. inflation is slowing and bond yields are falling…”
So far, so good. Makin, though, then begins to generate some
confusion when he turns his attention to a recent IMF report. He writes:
“Underscoring the widespread confusion about the use of
fiscal austerity, the IMF's Fiscal Monitor, after charging the
United States with tightening fiscal policy too rapidly, singled it out as
among the 10 countries with ‘the most severe fiscal problems,’ suggesting that
it still needs to agree on medium-term deficit reduction targets.
“The IMF Fiscal Monitor prescriptions for
the United States are badly muddled and ignore significant changes in its
fiscal stance. The decried sequester does cut annual spending next year by
about $120 billion if it is not rescinded by a nervous and confused-no thanks
to the IMF-Congress. Let us hope the sequester is left in place, providing as
it does a modest $1.2 trillion worth of spending cuts (only about 2.5 percent
of federal spending over the next decade).”
Makin appears to be criticizing the IMF for saying that,
while the U.S. has implemented too much austerity in the here and now, it is
not doing enough about the deficit in the “medium term.” This view can be
criticized, but Makin’s does not make entirely clear his reasons for
disagreeing with the IMF. He does say that the IMF ignores the progress that
has been made in cutting the budget deficit in the next few years, though Makin
just assumes, with no explanation, that this is good policy. He then turns his attention to the sequester,
which he claims to be a “modest” budget cut, but one which he approves. Why? He
does not say, but there seems to be an implicit assumption that his audience
shares his view that cutting budget spending is usually good idea, even if done
in a thoughtless way. Note that he has not prepared the ground for this,
because his earlier discussion said there was doubt that austerity is a good
idea. He does not give a reason why “modest” austerity is then a good idea; he
just assumes it. Perhaps that is a given in the lunchroom at AEI, but it is not
elsewhere. And his earlier statements about austerity might not meet with AEI lunchroom
approval.
Another Makin opinion that may not sit well in some
Republican circles is his statement that “fiscal austerity has been moderate
and probably, at the current pace of deficit reduction of about $300 billion
per year over the next half decade, has proceeded far enough for now.” In fact,
some liberals disagree with this too, believing that the current priority
should be growth and that requires increased government spending in a time of
lagging private sector demand. In this paper, Makin does not provide a
rationale for his position. Why is some austerity called for now, but just the
current amount? The reader has no way of knowing what type of economic model Makin
is relying on for his judgments.
Makin does take pain, though, to burnish his conservative
credibility by criticizing the President’s budget proposal. He claims “it does
not advance the fiscal debate.” Really? One may agree or disagree with the Administration’s
proposals – and plenty of liberals disagree with some parts of the Administration’s
budget – but to say there is no debate to be had here makes no sense. Reading
on, it becomes clear what Makin really means. According to his analysis, the
Administration’s budget does not reduce the deficit – in his words, advance us
on “the road to sustainable fiscal policy.” In other words, the Administration
does not advance the fiscal debate because Makin does not agree with what the
Administration has proposed. And, he still has not explained why deficit
reduction right now is more important than growth-oriented policy. Unlike some
fiscal hawks, Makin is not one who argues that deficit reduction is pro-growth.
He writes:
“… It is necessary to remember that placing the United
States on a sustainable fiscal path after four years of trillion-dollar
deficits will have consequences in the short term. Coupled with a ‘tax’ of
about $90 billion from higher oil prices, the total of fiscal and oil drag
prior to sequester is about $270 billion, and $45 billion in 2013 sequester
raised that to $315 billion, or nearly 2 percent of GDP. That drag needs to be
contrasted with average fiscal thrust of nearly 3 percentage points of GDP over
2009-12.
“The ‘fiscal swing’ of 5 percentage points of average 2009-12
fiscal thrust of 3 percent of GDP to 2013's 2 percent of GDP drag means that a
sharp US slowdown may occur in mid-2013, notwithstanding the heartening signs
of growth in the housing sector and a strong push from rising stock prices, all
occurring while interest rates remain remarkably low. Still, Congress should
not try to reverse deficit reduction progress as the president's budget has in
effect suggested. Sequestration will be blamed for any slowdown, but really the
cause will be a swing from steady previous stimulus to about $225 billion of
fiscal drag along with some bad luck supplied by about $90 billion in higher
energy costs.”
This leaves the reader still puzzling why this “fiscal drag”
is a good idea, even if factors other than the sequester contribute more to the
drag. Why should the government (Congress and the Administration) not pursue in
a slowing economy policies generating “fiscal thrust”? Makin assumes we know
the answer to that, but readers who do not instinctively share this belief are
left puzzled. One wonders how Makin would articulate his position on this if
challenged, which I assume is not likely to happen at AEI’s offices in
Washington, DC.
Finally, when it comes to deficit reduction, it is clear
that Makin prefers spending cuts to tax increases. That is a defensible
ideological position, especially if one’s political philosophy leads one to the
conclusion that the government’s role is currently too large. But if you are
going to contend that one is preferable to the other in terms of the impact on
the economy, then one should have an economic argument to back up this
assertion. Here is what Makin says:
“Republicans will decry the January 2013 tax increases as
crippling the economy and vow to allow no more. Democrats will decry the
sequester spending cuts and vow to allow no more spending cuts without tax
increases. The president has already proposed rescinding the sequester. The
reality the current weak economy is demonstrating is that further tax increases
to replace the deficit reduction by the sequester as proposed by the president
would weaken the economy even further.”
Makin gives no reason for the contention in the last
sentence. Why is that? My guess is that this paper is not really meant as an
objective view of the fiscal situation and economic outlook. The evidence is
that Makin is perfectly capable of good economic analysis if that is what he
wanted to do. Rather, the purpose of this article is to convince Republicans
that budget austerity has gone far enough for now. The political reality is
that Makin has no hope in convincing them to reverse course, and he knows that.
He is worried, though, that additional austerity would be devastating and is
trying to convince Republicans in Congress of that while making statements that
preserve his conservative credibility. He does not have to justify these
statements to his intended target audience.
We are left, though, wondering what Makin actually believes.
He may well believe that the current amount of austerity is correct and that
increasing taxes and cutting the amount of the sequester by equal amounts is
bad policy. Since he gives no reasons, we are left to wonder.
Personal Note: Early
in my career I met John Makin, though I doubt he remembers me. He did some
consulting work for the Treasury when I was working on U.S. balance of payment
issues. He was trying to use a statistical methodology (Box-Jenkins) to predict
the large statistical discrepancy that is put on the capital account side to
make the capital and current account balances offset each other exactly, as
they must from an accounting perspective. I also ran across him, I believe, in
earlier jobs I had in international monetary research at Treasury and at the Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco.