For now the Greek saga that was commanding front-page
headlines has receded to judge by the news coverage. In its place have come
more up-to-the-minute stories, such as the Iranian nuclear deal, the opening of
embassies in Washington and Havana, and the latest outrageous statements of
Donald Trump. The reduction in news prominence of Greece’s travails in the
Eurozone is understandable. After all, the Eurozone countries and Greece have
reached a tentative deal and an agreement to finalize that deal. (Of course,
all this will be followed by more talks when current deals become clearly
impossible for the Greeks to fulfill.) The banks have now reopened, albeit with
strict limits on cash withdrawals and economy-crippling capital controls still
in place. During this time as the new deal is finalized, the Europeans have
extended a €7.16 billion bridge loan to the Greek government, which
they have used to pay their creditors, including the IMF and the ECB.
Nevertheless, for those of us who have followed the progress
the Europeans have made in forming “an ever closer union” over the decades, the
recent Greek saga provides both fascination and horror. Fascination, because it
is inherently interesting. The experiment of a monetary union of nineteen
sovereign countries is unprecedented, and a crisis, however predictable,
provides a storyline that proves irresistible for those of us interested in
this sort of thing. The horror comes from the suffering of the Greeks, the
seemingly mistaken negotiating tactics of the new Greek government, the
stupidity of their European counterparties who fail to act in their own
interests, as correctly understood (to borrow a Realpolitik concept), and the very real danger that the European
project will shift into reverse. This all is consequential and the implications
for Europe and the world are much greater than the fate of a small country
(albeit beautiful and with charming and friendly inhabitants) in the European
“periphery.”
I always thought that the adoption of the euro was
premature. The countries involved were too different, and adopting a uniform
monetary policy for countries with different economic and social policies and
different cultures and languages seemed as asking for problems. Those
spearheading the drive for greater European unification of course knew this;
they hoped that problems as they arose with the euro would serve for greater
harmonization of policies in other spheres.
What was surprising was that the euro did as well as it did
for as long as it did. It was even conceivable that it could be a competitor to
the U.S. dollar as the reserve currency of choice. The economic crisis
beginning in 2008 changed all that, and the euro flaws became easy to see.
While various countries in what is called the periphery had and have problems
which have been made more difficult to manage because devaluation of one’s home
currency is not an option, the Greek situation has become the most difficult
for the Eurozone countries. It poses starkly the question of whether the
strategy of
achieving a closer union through engrenage
is now failing and whether the movement toward an ever closer union will now
shift into reverse.
The Greek crisis has not only put the conceptual problems
with the euro in bold relief; it also has shown the inadequacy of the economic
theories, such as they are, of the leadership of the dominant country in EU,
Germany, and that of some of the other northern and former Soviet bloc
countries following Germany’s lead. Clearly, the policy of using austerity to
solve debt problems has not worked. In Greece’s case, it has made the debt
problem worse. The denominator of the ratio everyone looks at, debt to GDP, has
been falling, meaning that the ratio has been increasing. The austerity of the
past five years has prolonged and worsened Greece’s recession, turning it into
a depression. Greece also does not have the option of trying to offset the
decreased demand from austerity with a looser monetary policy than its main
trading partners, given the euro. Judging from a presentation German finance
minister Wolfgang Schäuble made earlier this year at Brookings, he apparently
believes that austerity will generate confidence that a country is getting its
fiscal house in order. This confidence will lead to greater investment and
hence growth. Neither conventional macro nor experience provides justification
or evidence that in the face of double-digit unemployment that this is correct.
Moreover, the worsening debts to GDP ratios due to slower economic growth most
likely have the opposite effect on confidence.
But beliefs die hard. The Eurogroup insisted on continued
austerity for Greece, along with reforms to certain laws which arguably will
give Greece a more efficient and competitive economy. While these may help the
Greek economy once the current depression is over, it is hard to see how
reforms to certain uncompetitive laws will help Greece get out of its current
slump.
Also, the Eurogroup played rough with Greece during the
negotiations. For example, it has been reported that Dutch finance minister and Eurogroup president
Jeroen Dijsselbloem told Greek finance minister Yanis Varoufakis that, if he
did not agree to the Eurogroup demands, “your economy is going to collapse...We
are going to collapse your banks.”
As it turned out, this was no idle threat. On
Sunday, June 28, the European Central Bank (“ECB”) announced that it would
not raise the amount of Emergency Liquidity Assistance (“ELA”) that the Bank of
Greece could extend as collateralized loans to Greek banks. This was the day
after Prime Minister Tsipras announced that he would submit the terms of the
latest offer from the Eurogroup in a referendum on July 5. The restriction on
ELA loans led to the closure of Greek banks on the following Monday, withdrawal
limits of €60 a day, and capital controls. After Greek voters overwhelmingly
rejected the latest (and by then defunct) offer of the Eurogroup imposing austerity
on the Greek economy in a much watched referendum vote on July 5, the
ECB again said on the next day that it would not raise the ELA amount and
would “adjust” (i.e., raise) the
haircuts on Greek government debt serving as collateral. This essentially brought
the Greek economy to its knees, and a probably panicked Alex Tsipras agreed to
even harsher terms than the Greek voters had rejected on July 13.
While the Eurogroup led by Schäuble and Dijsselbloem played
very rough with Greece, it is fair to criticize the Greek government for its
negotiating tactics. The economic arguments that the Greek officials were
making made more sense than that of their more strident interlocutors, but the
abrasiveness with which they conducted themselves and the call for a referendum
look in retrospect to have been mistakes. It did not get them anything, except
perhaps a worse deal than was originally obtainable.
On this point, though, John
Cassidy of The New Yorker argues
that “Syriza’s surrender wasn’t necessarily an ignominious one.” The reason is
that this episode points out the necessity for change in Europe, thus, perhaps,
paving the way for that change:
In the
Marxist intellectual tradition, from which many senior members of Syriza hail,
progress comes about gradually. To overthrow the existing order, you have to
first mobilize the masses by stripping back the democratic veil and showing the
real workings of the system: only then will the “objective conditions” be ripe
for revolutionary change. Tsipras and Syriza didn’t create the conditions for
change. But in bringing Greece to the brink, and demonstrating that its
creditors were willing to see it collapse if it didn’t buckle to their demands,
they did, arguably, succeed in showing up the eurozone as a deflationary straightjacket
dominated by creditors. And they did this with all of the world watching. “One
must know who the enemy is, in order to fight the enemy,” Alex Andreou, a Greek
blogger who is sympathetic to Tsipras, wrote last week. “Syriza has achieved
that. Now, it is over to you, Spain. Take what we’ve learned and apply it
wisely.”
Having followed the developments, I do not think that
Tsipras had such a devious negotiating strategy in mind. Cassidy is correct,
though, that the outcome of the negotiations, with more still to come, has
highlighted problems with the euro and EU governance. This growing realization
may bring change, but what kind of change is uncertain. Cassidy concludes his
article by quoting Tsipras’s comment to the Greek parliament that “this fight
will bear fruit,” but goes on to write: “Only time will tell if that was
wishful thinking.”
Another interesting disagreement that the Greek crisis
revealed is the irrevocability of a country’s decision to use the euro.
Interestingly, Schäuble has made no secret of his desire for Greece to give up
the euro, at least temporarily. For him, this is not an immediate cost issue,
since he argues that Greece leaving the euro would make it possible to forgive
some of Greece’s debt and he says that the EU would provide Greece humanitarian
aid during the monetary transition.
Schäuble’s preference for Greece to leave the euro is not
new. For example, Andrew Ross Sorkin of The
New York Times wrote an
article at the end of June discussing a conversation in July 2012 between
Schäuble and then Secretary of the Treasury Tim Geithner on this subject.
Geithner reported in this conversation in his book, Stress Tests: Reflections on Financial Crises. Geithner was
visiting Schäuble at his vacation home on an island in the North Sea. They had
been discussing how to keep Greece in the Eurozone, but then, according to the
article:
To Mr. Geithner’s dismay, however, Mr. Schäuble took
the conversation in a different direction.
“He told me
there were many in Europe who still thought kicking the Greeks out of the
eurozone was a plausible — even desirable — strategy,” Mr. Geithner later
recounted in his memoir, “Stress Test: Reflections on Financial Crises.” “The
idea was that with Greece out, Germany would be more likely to provide the
financial support the eurozone needed because the German people would no longer
perceive aid to Europe as a bailout for the Greeks,” he says in the memoir.
“At the
same time, a Grexit would be traumatic enough that it would help scare the rest
of Europe into giving up more sovereignty to a stronger banking and fiscal
union,” Mr. Geithner wrote. “The argument was that letting Greece burn would
make it easier to build a stronger Europe with a more credible firewall.”
Fast-forward three years. What Mr. Schäuble
articulated that summer afternoon to Mr. Geithner is finally taking shape.
This is interesting, since many
economists, most prominently Paul Krugman, have argued that Greece would be
better off leaving the euro. Krugman is no fan of the austerity Schäuble has
prescribed for Greece and other countries with debt problems, but there seems
to be some common ground between him and Schäuble on the question of Greece and
the euro.
From an economic perspective, the argument that Greece
should leave the euro is strong. That, though, has to be at least somewhat
tempered by politics, because the motivation for creating the euro was
politics, not economics. The determination of many leaders in Europe to keep
the Eurozone intact should not be underestimated, though it will be severely
tested in the coming months and years. German Chancellor Angela Merkel
disagrees with her finance minister on the desirability of keeping Greece in
the Eurozone. Also, disagreeing is ECB Mario Draghi (“whatever
it takes”). At a press conference on July 16 (after the Greek parliament
vote on the deal) in which Draghi announced that the ECB would increase the
amount of ELA lending the Bank of Greece can make to Greek banks by €900
million, he said (according
to Bloomberg): “We always acted on the assumption that Greece will remain a
member of the euro area. There was never a question.”
The crisis also brought about a noticeable rift between the
two key countries of the EU, France and Germany. France, along with Italy, is
more sympathetic to the problems Greece faces and is more willing than Germany
to offer concessions in order to preserve the Eurozone and not set the
precedent of a country giving up the common currency.
The vision of an ever closer union seems more distant, and,
as for Schäuble, it is not clear what his vision is. A Europe in which Germany
is viewed as being able to dictate policy is not sustainable. There will be a
reaction against that; in fact, there already is. The uncertainty of Britain’s
continued membership in the EU is more open to question, with
some leftist voices, seeing the Greek debacle, having doubts about the
benefit of membership, along with politicians on the right who have long held
that position.
Most observers believe that the targets for primary
surpluses will be impossible for Greece to meet. A new Greek crisis is likely.
Whether the EU will end up putting off difficult decisions (“kicking the can
down the road”) when that crisis arrives is uncertain. What can be said,
though, is that the intransigence of Germany and some other Eurozone countries
has put the European project in doubt.
No comments:
Post a Comment