On February 4, the Congressional Budget Office
released a report, The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2014
to 2024. It immediately created a furor, not
because of the main report or its general projections but because of an eleven
page appendix (Appendix
C, “Labor Market Effects of the Affordable Care Act: Updated Estimates”).
The CBO was probably a bit taken aback by the reaction in political and policy
analysis circles and in the news and opinion media. Evidently feeling it
necessary to clarify what the CBO had said, the CBO’s Director, Doug Elmendorf,
posted on the CBO’s website on February 10 a piece entitled “Frequently Asked
Questions About CBO’s Estimates of the Labor Market Effects of the Affordable
Care Act”, in order to clarify that they
did not mean that 2.5 million people would “lose their jobs in 2024 because of
the ACA” (Affordable Care Act).
The sentence critics of the ACA jumped on stated: “The reduction in CBO’s projections of hours worked [due to the ACA] represents a decline in the number of full time equivalent workers of about 2.0 million in 2017, rising to about 2.5 million in 2024.” Republican politicians immediately denounced the ACA as a job killer, and initially the media played along. When the media finally realized that the Republican characterization of the report was misleading at best, or just plain wrong, they subsequently wrote better articles. Nevertheless, some, most notably Chris Cillizza, a political reporter for the Washington Post, wrote a much ridiculed post for his Washington Post blog, “The Fix” (a reference to political junkies). Cillizza argued that it did not really matter what the facts were for a political analyst like himself; what is important is voters’ perceptions. He wrote: “My job is to assess not the rightness of each argument but to deal in the real world of campaign politics in which perception often (if not always) trumps reality. I deal in the world as voters believe it is, not as I (or anyone else) thinks it should be.”
The sentence critics of the ACA jumped on stated: “The reduction in CBO’s projections of hours worked [due to the ACA] represents a decline in the number of full time equivalent workers of about 2.0 million in 2017, rising to about 2.5 million in 2024.” Republican politicians immediately denounced the ACA as a job killer, and initially the media played along. When the media finally realized that the Republican characterization of the report was misleading at best, or just plain wrong, they subsequently wrote better articles. Nevertheless, some, most notably Chris Cillizza, a political reporter for the Washington Post, wrote a much ridiculed post for his Washington Post blog, “The Fix” (a reference to political junkies). Cillizza argued that it did not really matter what the facts were for a political analyst like himself; what is important is voters’ perceptions. He wrote: “My job is to assess not the rightness of each argument but to deal in the real world of campaign politics in which perception often (if not always) trumps reality. I deal in the world as voters believe it is, not as I (or anyone else) thinks it should be.”
David Weigel of Slate,
responded
to Cillizza by writing: “Now, if we're talking or
reporting on what Republicans are saying at this moment, true: They're talking
about the CBO report. What will we be reporting on a few months from now?
What'll the attack be? We
don't know.” Ezra Klein, Cillizza’s former colleague at the Post, wrote
on his public Facebook page:
“I don't quite understand the model of politics
underlying the backlash-to-the-backlash over the CBO report. The theory is that
though the GOP's initial spin on the report was wrong it's meta-right because
the lies will be used to power effective attack ads in the fall -- and in
politics, what's true, and what voters can be tricked into believing is true,
are two equally valid categories for inquiry…
“Obamacare is an unpopular law that suffered from a
disastrous launch. Does anyone think the GOP would've been unable to find a way
to write devastating attack copy about it if that CBO report hadn't come out?
Of course not.
“The parties often don't have enough money to air the attacks ads they want to air. They often lack candidates with the credibility to make the attack ads stick. They're often lack the economic conditions that predispose the electorate to listen to them. They're typically chasing voters who lack any interest in watching another nasty political commercial.
“There are plenty of real scarcities in American politics that could really change elections if one party or the other solved them. But "things to say in an attack ad" just isn't one of those scarcities.”
“The parties often don't have enough money to air the attacks ads they want to air. They often lack candidates with the credibility to make the attack ads stick. They're often lack the economic conditions that predispose the electorate to listen to them. They're typically chasing voters who lack any interest in watching another nasty political commercial.
“There are plenty of real scarcities in American politics that could really change elections if one party or the other solved them. But "things to say in an attack ad" just isn't one of those scarcities.”
In his blog post, Doug Elmendorf wrote:
“Q: Will 2.5 Million People Lose Their Jobs in 2024
Because of the ACA?
“A: No, we would not describe our estimates in that
way...
“Because the longer-term reduction in work is expected
to come almost entirely from a decline in the amount of labor that workers
choose to supply in response to the changes in their incentives, we do not
think it is accurate to say that the reduction stems from people ‘losing’ their
jobs.
“Here’s a useful way to think about the choice of
wording: When firms do not have enough business and decide to lay people off,
the people who are laid off are generally worse off and are therefore unhappy
about what is happening. As a result, other people express their sympathy to
those people for having “lost their jobs” due to forces beyond their control.
In contrast, when the labor market is strong and people decide on their own to
retire, to leave work to take care of their families, or to cut back on their
hours to pursue other interests, those people presumably think they are better
off (or they would not be making the voluntary choices they are making). As a
result, other people are generally happy for them and do not describe them as
having ‘lost their jobs.’
“Thus, there is a critical difference between, on
the one hand, people who leave a job for reasons beyond their control and, on
the other hand, people who choose not to work or to work less. The wording that
people use to describe those differing circumstances reflects the different
reactions of the people involved. In our report, we indicated that ‘the
estimated reduction [in employment] stems almost entirely from a net decline in
the amount of labor that workers choose to supply,’ so we think the language of
‘losing a job’ does not fit…
“There is a broader question as to whether the
society and the economy will be better off as a result of those choices being
made available. Even though the individuals making decisions to work less
presumably feel that they will be happier as a result of those decisions, total
employment, investment, output, and tax revenue will be smaller. (Those effects
are included in CBO’s budget and economic projections under current law.) To be
sure, the health insurance system in place prior to the ACA generated its own
distortions to people’s work decisions, but many of the decisions to work less
under the ACA will be made possible by government-funded subsidies, the burden
of which will be borne largely by other people. Moreover, people’s decisions
about work are also affected by taxes and benefit programs apart from those
related to health insurance. Hence, whether voluntary reductions in hours
worked owing to the ACA are good or bad for the country as a whole is a matter of
judgment.
“A tradeoff of this sort—although not necessarily of
the same magnitude—is intrinsic in any effort to significantly increase health
insurance coverage or to provide other types of benefits that are aimed at
low-income people. As we wrote in the report: ‘Subsidies that help lower-income
people purchase an expensive product like health insurance must be relatively
large to encourage a significant proportion of eligible people to enroll. If
those subsidies are phased out with rising income …, the phaseout effectively …
discourage[es] work.’ Again, the best way to address that tradeoff is a matter
of judgment.”
As it turns out, the hue and cry over what the CBO
said about the ACA and jobs has died down. The media appears to have some
remorse in the way they initially reported the story and Republican politicians
who have mischaracterized the CBO report have been pilloried by liberal
political websites. The story for the most part has disappeared, at least for
now.
Still, there has been some more intelligent
commentary from some critics of the ACA. The argument they make is that the
ACA’s phase out of health care subsidies as lower income people earn more
income acts like an implicit marginal tax and discourages work. (For example,
see these blog posts from Charles
Blahous and Keith
Hennessey.) This is in fact the main reason the CBO cites for
its estimate of the reduction in labor supply.
If one looks at the structure of the subsidies for
health insurance bought on the exchanges, the phaseouts are poorly constructed.
In some cases, an extra dollar of income would mean a loss of a subsidy of more
than a dollar if one’s income is just below the cutoff level for the subsidy.
However, in general, the amount of subsidy that an individual gives up with
extra income appears to be in the neighborhood of 10 to 16 percent of the
additional income. (One can play around with examples with this handy subsidy
calculator at the Kaiser Family Foundation website.) The
subsidies end at 400 percent of the Federal Poverty Level (“FPL”). Income is defined to
be modified
adjusted gross income. (For 2013, the FPL was $11,490 for a single adult
and $23,550 for a family of four.)
It is not clear how the CBO estimated how much this
would reduce the amount of labor supplied either by workers reducing the number
of hours worked or dropping out of the labor market entirely. While
significant, these implicit marginal tax rates by themselves are neither huge
nor confiscatory. Also, it is worth remembering that one cannot live on health
insurance subsidies alone. People who drop out of the labor force because of
the reduction in subsidies as their income increases need to have other sources
of income or wealth.
If workers take a full time job that provides health
insurance, they lose the subsidy. Whether or not that loss acts as an implicit
marginal tax from the point of view of the individual worker depends on the
particular facts. One would have to look at the change in the net cost of
health insurance premiums and expected out of pocket costs to do a full
analysis. To do this in the aggregate would seem to be a daunting task for
economic forecasters.
Also, it should be noted that for states that have
chosen to expand Medicaid, subsidies for health insurance begins at 138% of the
FPL. Below that amount, people get coverage through Medicaid. While losing
Medicaid can be viewed as a cost, it is hard to assign an implicit marginal tax
rate for earning income that crosses the 138% line, because the private health
insurance plans offered on the exchanges are likely to be much better than
Medicaid. The number of doctors who accept Medicaid is quite limited and there
can be severe frustrations, which differ among the states, in dealing with the
Medicaid bureaucracy. (There can be frustrations in dealing with private
insurance companies, but my impression is that these are probably not quite as
bad as dealing with some state bureaucracies and their legal processes.)
In states that have chosen not to expand Medicaid,
there will be people who will neither be eligible for exchange subsidies nor
Medicaid. For these people, the law will provide an incentive to work at least enough,
if they can, to get to the 138% of FPL in order to benefit from the subsidy.
Finally, people who are covered by Medicare are not
eligible for the subsidies provided for health insurance on the exchanges.
As many have pointed out in the discussion of the CB0
report, means testing a government benefit leads to an increase in implicit
marginal taxes until the benefit is totally phased out. This is not new to the
ACA. For example, welfare benefits, the earned income tax credit, and food
stamps are all subject to means testing. What would be useful for policy
analysis would be a comprehensive analysis of means-tested government programs,
along with federal, state, and local income taxes, and what this might mean to
particular classes of workers. Conservatives are of course right when they say
that high marginal tax rates discourage additional work. Devising solutions to
this issue is not simple.
However, focusing on the ACA in isolation and
criticizing it for this does not do much to advance solutions. Some critics of
the ACA would like to go back to the status
quo ante, but that is not going to happen. Other critics would like to
reduce health care coverage substantially for poor people by giving everybody
the same fixed amount (a “refundable” tax credit) to buy private health
insurance. That also is not going to happen.
As far as what the ACA does to economic growth, this
is unclear. In the first instance, as the CBO admits, there is “substantial
uncertainty” concerning its estimates of the effects of the ACA on labor market
participation. Even taking the estimates as given, former Federal Reserve Vice
Chairman Alan Blinder writes
in the Wall Street Journal:
“…The CBO now estimates that the ACA will reduce
labor supply by about 1.5% to 2% over a decade. That's small and, arguably, a
good thing. Let's count it as antigrowth, though certainly not as a ‘job
killer.’ But what about the potential savings in health-care costs from the
ACA—which are clearly pro-growth?
“Remember, one of the principal objectives of
health-care reform is to slow down cost increases, thereby reducing the burdens
on both businesses and the federal budget. And health-care costs have indeed slowed
dramatically. The following little tidbit is buried deep in the CBO report, and
has gotten little attention: CBO ‘lowered their estimate of average premiums
for insurance coverage through exchanges in 2014 by about 15 percent.’ Let me
repeat that: 15% lower, just since last May. That's huge.”
As a final point, as long as we have substantial
unemployment, that the ACA reduces labor market participation should not be a
source of concern. Finally, I would note that many of those arguing that the
ACA is fatally flawed because of its effects on labor market participation and
economic growth also have been in favor of our current contractionary fiscal
policy, which has served to slow the recovery and which monetary policy cannot
totally counteract.
No comments:
Post a Comment