On January 29, Treasury auctioned its first issue of
floating rate notes. According to press reports, market participants and
analysts felt the auction went well. After all, total
bids (competitive and noncompetitive) amounted to almost $85 billion for an
issue size of $15 billion, which is very good coverage.
The spread the Treasury will pay over the 13-week
Treasury bill on these two-year notes is 0.045%. This spread is added to the
latest 13-week Treasury bill rate determined at auction, meaning that the
interest rate on the floating rate notes changes weekly and is paid out
quarterly. (For more details, see the final
rule for these securities.) With this spread, the floating rate notes are
currently yielding about double the current rates on 13-week bills. It is less
than the rate on 2-year notes, which are yielding in the neighborhood of 0.3%,
and about equal to the one-month Treasury yield curve rate published
by the Treasury.
Given that floating rate notes are effectively one-week
instruments, I would agree that this auction produced a fair result. Also, in
the current low interest rate environment, the floating rate notes are not
likely to be a significant factor in either decreasing or increasing Treasury’s
interest costs.
As readers of this blog know, I have not viewed the
introduction of floating rate notes favorably. (For example, see this post.)
One argument for them is that they are a way to extend the maturity of the
public debt. The reasons for extending the maturity of the public debt are to
lessen rollover risk and to reduce the variability of interest payments. As I noted
in the linked post, the Treasury has never had a problem in rolling over bills
in modern times, and floating rate notes do nothing to reduce fluctuation of
interest payments due to changing market conditions.
I was surprised to see that usually astute Gillian
Tett of the Financial Times seems
confused on the latter point in an
article of hers recently. She wrote:
“…this benefit [of borrowing short-term] comes with
a sting that mortgage borrowers know well: if rates increase, interest payments
could balloon. And if investors panic about inflation, higher rates or fiscal
sustainability, that squeeze could be more intense.
“The good news is that the Treasury is aware of this
danger, and trying to prepare. In recent months it has had success in raising
the average maturity profile by selling more long-term bonds. This stands at
66.7 months, and officials say that by 2020 it could reach 80.
“Treasury officials are also trying to help the
market absorb future rate rises by offering a more flexible range of
instruments. This week’s experiment with floaters is one move…”
Another reason to issue floating rate notes is to
broaden the appeal of Treasury securities to new investors. I think this
argument had some merit in making the case for Treasury issuing
inflation-indexed securities, since inflation-indexation made for a different
asset class, though I am not certain how significant this has been. With
floating rate notes, I am doubtful. These seem to be mainly designed to appeal
to existing investors, such as money market mutual funds, for which there is a
clear benefit. While Treasury does not have any problems rolling over
securities, it is bit of a hassle for investors to have to rollover their
maturing securities. Also, in the current climate, possible disruptions to
Treasury’s auction schedule when Congress has not passed the debt limit in a
timely matter may be of some concern to investors in short-term Treasury
securities. Perhaps, money market mutual funds should bid aggressively for
floating rate notes, giving Treasury a break in the yield, since there are
clear advantages to them from these securities.
Finally, I would like to make one general point. In
recent years, there has been instability in Treasury’s debt management
strategy. During the Clinton and George W. Bush administrations, there were
efforts to shorten the average maturity of the public debt, in addition to the
decision by the Clinton Administration to issue inflation-indexed securities,
an idea which had been rejected by previous Democratic and Republican
administrations. The decision to shorten the average maturity of the public
debt was pursued aggressively by the George W. Bush Administration with its
decision to eliminate the issuance of 30-year bonds, a decision that was
subsequently reversed after the major Treasury proponent of this, Under
Secretary Peter Fisher, left Treasury.
The argument for shortening the average maturity of
the public debt was that Treasury long-term yields are usually higher than
short-term yields and that the Treasury would save money over time and interest
rate cycle by issuing more short-term securities. That rationale was rejected
by the Obama Administration, which decided to extend the maturity of the public
debt during a time of historically low interest rates. The decision to issue
floating rate notes does not fit neatly into the lengthening strategy, but it
has been portrayed that way.
Of course, it is not the President who is making
these decisions but the Treasury Secretary and political appointees at Treasury.
While it is hard to ascribe motives, it appears that at least some political
appointees wanted to leave their mark on debt management, which is usually,
absent a debt limit problem or other crisis, a fairly low profile, though
critical, task. In the broad scheme of things, the instability of debt
management brought about by different political appointees is probably not that
important, but it is not an optimum way to operate.
No comments:
Post a Comment